Myths About
Quantitative Easing
Some of the money for these government expenditures has come
directly from "money printing" by the central bank, also known as "quantitative
easing." For over a decade, the Bank of Japan
has been engaged in this practice; yet the hyperinflation that deficit hawks said
it would trigger has not occurred. To
the contrary, as noted by Wolf
Richter in a May 9, 2012 article:
[T]he Japanese [are] in fact among the few people in the world enjoying actual price stability, with interchanging periods of minor inflation and minor deflation--as opposed to the 27% inflation per decade that the Fed has conjured up and continues to call, moronically, "price stability."
He cites as evidence the following graph from the Japanese Ministry of Internal Affairs:
How is that possible? It all
depends on where the money generated by quantitative easing ends up. In Japan, the money borrowed by the government
has found its way back into the pockets of the Japanese people in the form of
social security and interest on their savings.
Money in consumer bank accounts stimulates demand, stimulating the production
of goods and services, increasing supply; and when supply and demand rise
together, prices remain stable.
Myths
About the "Lost Decade"
Japan's finances have long been shrouded in secrecy, perhaps because
when the country was more open about printing money and using it to support its
industries, it got embroiled in World War II. In his 2008 book In the Jaws of the Dragon , Fingleton suggests that Japan feigned insolvency in
the "lost decade" of the 1990s to avoid drawing the ire of protectionist
Americans for its booming export trade in automobiles and other products. Belying the weak reported statistics, Japanese
exports increased by 73% during that decade, foreign assets increased, and electricity
use increased by 30%, a tell-tale indicator of a flourishing industrial sector. By 2006, Japan's exports were three times
what they were in 1989.
The Japanese government has maintained the faà §ade of complying with
international banking regulations by "borrowing" money rather than "printing" it
outright. But borrowing money issued by
the government's own central bank is the functional equivalent of the
government printing it, particularly when the debt is just carried on the books
and never paid back.
Implications
for the "Fiscal Cliff"
All of this has implications for Americans concerned with an
out-of-control national debt. Properly
managed and directed, it seems, the debt need be nothing to fear. Like Japan, and unlike Greece and other Eurozone
countries, the U.S. is the sovereign issuer of its own currency. If it wished, Congress could fund its budget without
resorting to foreign creditors or private banks. It could do this either by issuing the money
directly or by borrowing from its own central bank, effectively interest-free, since
the Fed rebates its profits to the government after deducting its costs.
A little quantitative easing can be a good thing, if the money winds up with the government and the people rather than simply in the reserve accounts of banks. The national debt can also be a good thing. As Federal Reserve Board Chairman Marriner Eccles testified in hearings before the House Committee on Banking and Currency in 1941, government credit (or debt) "is what our money system is. If there were no debts in our money system, there wouldn't be any money."
Properly directed, the national debt becomes the spending money of the people. It stimulates demand, stimulating
productivity. To keep the system stable
and sustainable, the money just needs to come from the nation's own government
and its own people, and needs to return to the government and people.
(Note: You can view every article as one long page if you sign up as an Advocate Member, or higher).