235 online
 
Most Popular Choices
Share on Facebook 107 Printer Friendly Page More Sharing Summarizing
Exclusive to OpEd News:
OpEdNews Op Eds    H2'ed 2/5/21

Should Balanced Approval Voting be Simplified?

By       (Page 1 of 1 pages)   8 comments, In Series: Balanced Voting

Paul Cohen
Follow Me on Twitter     Message Paul Cohen
Become a Fan
  (3 fans)

Tis a gift to be simple
Tis a gift to be simple
(Image by A_Peach from flickr)
  Details   DMCA
Ranked voting systems are difficult for voters to comprehend. Ranking all of the candidates makes voting difficult and the counting of ballots is also demanding. BAV is a much simpler system of voting, but still, it is a bit more complex than plurality voting or even than balanced plurality voting. So we might ask whether it is possible to simplify BAV. We show here that, while some simplification is an option, it would come with some cost to democratic outcomes and probably also to voter satisfaction.

In an early article of this series, where we first defined BAV, we also considered a voting system that I then called BV-1 (but which now I generally call balanced plurality voting). As with plurality voting, a BV-1 voter must choose only a single candidate to evaluate, but that voter can choose whether to vote in support or in opposition to the chosen candidate. BV-2 voting is similar, but the voter can choose up to two candidates to evaluate. And the notation generalizes, with for example BV-5 allowing the voter to choose as many as five candidates and mark each of them as support or opposition. To be clear, however, multiple votes for a single candidate are not allowed in any of these BV-systems; for example BV5 cannot be used in an election with fewer than five candidates. It is worth notice, however, that for example, in an election with exactly five candidates, BV-5 amounts precisely to BAV; with ten candidates it is BV-10 that is equivalent to BAV.

In previous articles (such as in this recent one) we have seen that BAV is incompatible with a polarized two-party duopoly; but it is easy to see that the argument for this fact works even with BV-2 taking the place of BAV. The argument is that with a polarized two-party duopoly and with the candidates roughly sharing equally all of the votes, the two dominant-party candidates will each be supported by roughly half of the voters as well as opposed by roughly the half of voters who support the other candidate. So with BV-2 voting each will have nearly a net zero vote tally. This makes it easy for a new political party to gain a credible position of viability.

Could there might be an analogue of the polarized duopoly with more parties, say just three so that BV-3 would be needed? First we should clarify what is meant by a polarized electorate. The argument for BV-2 makes use of the polarized two-party duopoly to conclude that all (or nearly all) voters who support one of the two candidates will oppose the other. This leads us to the notion that in a three-way polarized electorate, a voter who supports one of the candidates will oppose both of the other candidates. More generally, an n-way polarized electorate is one in which supporters of one of the n candidates will oppose all of the n-1 other candidates. With this understanding, it is the word polarized that is critical for the argument and not so much the word duopoly.

Using BV-3 voting, if there are three or more candidates then the three candidates from the polarized triple of parties will each receive support from approximately 33% of the voters but opposition from 66% of the voters resulting in a negative net vote. A hidden assumption here is that this is a stable three-party situation; otherwise at least one of the three parties would not be viewed as viable.

Of course all of this generalizes to higher numbers than three. But it should be apparent that as the number, of parties grows, the likelihood of a polarized electorate lessens. With voters having many choices of candidates, even a voter who has a clear favorite might also have a second choice or maybe a third so that the voter would decide not to vote against (and perhaps even support) candidates beyond just the voter's first choice. Moreover, with many available candidates, the winning tally will tend to be fairly small and that alone will open the door for additional candidates to enter the competition.

From these considerations, might it seem sensible to adopt BV-3 or BV-4 in place of BAV? After all, these alternative systems do appear to make the counting of votes a bit easier. But are there other considerations?

The downside of course is that voter options are also restricted. Some voters may feel forced into uncomfortable decisions such as choosing which three candidates to evaluate when four of them seem equally satisfactory. In a recent article, I suggested that when a voter is forced into making arbitrary choices, the voter is apt to consider factors such as electability in deciding how to vote. It would much be more in concert with democratic values if elections could serve as a measure of actual voter preferences among the candidates. Adoption of a specific BV-n system in place of BAV would conflict with this democratic objective.

And there are yet other perspectives from which to judge a voting system than merely the effect of the system on the political outcomes. In fact it seems that the way most people first consider a novel voting system, is on the basis of how satisfied they feel with it as a voter. An unnecessary restriction on the number of candidate to evaluate is sure to cause some dissatisfaction from voters, both when they first learn of the the system and later as they experience using it.

Rate It | View Ratings

Paul Cohen Social Media Pages: Facebook page url on login Profile not filled in       Twitter page url on login Profile not filled in       Linkedin page url on login Profile not filled in       Instagram page url on login Profile not filled in

Attended college thanks to the generous state support of education in 1960's America. Earned a Ph.D. in mathematics at the University of Illinois followed by post doctoral research positions at the Institute for Advanced Study in Princeton. (more...)
 

Go To Commenting
The views expressed herein are the sole responsibility of the author and do not necessarily reflect those of this website or its editors.
Writers Guidelines

 
Contact AuthorContact Author Contact EditorContact Editor Author PageView Authors' Articles
Support OpEdNews

OpEdNews depends upon can't survive without your help.

If you value this article and the work of OpEdNews, please either Donate or Purchase a premium membership.

STAY IN THE KNOW
If you've enjoyed this, sign up for our daily or weekly newsletter to get lots of great progressive content.
Daily Weekly     OpEd News Newsletter
Name
Email
   (Opens new browser window)
 

Most Popular Articles by this Author:     (View All Most Popular Articles by this Author)

Perverse Delivery Charges

Who Pays Taxes?

What Might be the Best Voting System?

What Could be Wrong with Ranked-Choice Voting?

Liberate Yourself from the Mainstream Media

Conservatives Without Conscience

To View Comments or Join the Conversation:

Tell A Friend